• home
  • what we do
  • blog
  • about us
  • contact
Darwin's Grove

Does Envy vs. Greed apply to Marketing?

10/23/2013

0 Comments

 
Picture
What if assumptions are wrong?   By a little? By a lot? These kind of what ifs can create interesting insights.  A recent example of testing big assumptions in finance may offer an interesting new perspective for marketing.

It’s not greed…
At the risk of simplifying too much,  financial models rely on the widely held assumption that greed drives the market.  But one theory submitted by Eric Falkenstein says Why Envy Dominates Greed.  While he goes on to build a compelling case in his book one of the clearest arguments is based on evolution and cognitive science.  Basically, the social nature of man is built on a capability to monitor relative status, hence envy, rather on the unbounded demands of uncapped needs, or greed.  Cognitively, if greed were dominant, we’d likely get mentally swamped in trying to make decisions allocating our resources and energies.And that little assumption can change a lot.

Falkenstein goes on to generate new financial models based on the changed assumption of envy with empirical testing that seems to show how this may be a real improvement to classical financial theory.

Picture
Are we making the same assumption in marketing?
Sales and Marketing have long used the model of the “funnel” to structure their efforts.   This notion of the funnel has a couple attributes which standout:
  • It assumes the customer proceeds through the funnel sequentially in a process of satisfying the need for consumption (a.k.a. greed)
  • The structure is built from the perspective of the organization’s view and the customer is, well, fodder.

If these assumptions are incorrect could it help us rethink how we structure sales and marketing?  Beyond greed or envy is there another way to view our ways of connection with the customer?  Could this help us rethink the funnel? 

More soon!

0 Comments

Anchoring, can we model it?

5/28/2013

0 Comments

 
We have decided to “warm-up” on Anchoring since a lot of people have either heard of it as well as have experienced it themselves.  During decision making anchoring occurs when an initial piece of information inappropriately influences subsequent decisions.  And understanding  Hierarchical Temporal Models (HTM) takes us a long way toward developing a useful model.

Anchoring gives us a sense that in decision making we are bringing a lot of parallel activity to bear to arrive at a conclusion.  We also suspect that encounters of sequential events must have affect our deliberations.

Does HTM work this way too?  Very much so.

Some key aspects of  how an HTM works:
  • Model Hierarchy. Models are learned by building on previous models and over time into a hierarchy of reusable models.  One can even think of memory and model as one in the same.  While the  potential for “memory” exists in the HTM (and likely our cortex), it is only when patterns have been built that we might really consider these real memories.
  • It’s all predictions.  Likewise memories & models are also simultaneously predictions.   A model seeks opportunities for confirmation every chance it gets.
  • Temporal structure. We often think of memories as static and spatial, like images- say of our cat.  And our power of recognition is exemplary (ie. satisfying the prediction “is that my cat?”).  But what is also baked in and less obvious is that models exist in association with many contexts (other models), and significatly those connected directly in time.  Yes, I am good a recognizing my wife’s voice saying “Hi, I’m home”, but she typcially returns around 5:30p and of course I am expecting (predicting) it.
  • Sparse representation. And finally memories, because they can be built from other models, can also be represented what we call very “sparsely”.  Combine pieces to get entirely new models very compactly, which at the same time explains the power,speed, and efficiency of the human cortex.

To simplify then:
  1. memory = model = prediction (and later also = action!),
  2. memory’s are also always wired in a temporal structure, and
  3. memories can be incredibly reliable and efficient because they are based on sparse representations.

Now we can play out some of the hypothetical ways and HTM helps us understand Anchoring.  In most anchoring experiments the two task are related somehow even though they technically have nothing to do with one another.  For example both may  involve numbers.   And of course, the two tasks are linked in time, one right after the other.  With the first task invoking models related to numbers and forming predictions, perhaps it is not surprising these models remain active and influential through the second estimation task.

And one other aspect comes to light.  And that is the value of making a wrong prediction.  As we said these sparse representations can quickly form complex models, in part by allowing less than perfect predictions to proceed.  In typical anchoring experiments the tasks at hand are not critical to survival for example.  It would be interesting to explore the anchoring bias relative to the importance of a decision and see if it breaks down there.  [Put another way,  “It doesn’t really matter what I put out there as an estimate, but it sure will be interesting to see if these two task were really linked in some way when I hear the answer!”]

Considering these aspects of the HTM then might let us predict how anchoring plays out.  It is likely:

  • The sequential nature of the tasks is essential to impacting the observable effect.
  • Finding further model links should strengthen the effect.  For example invoking the anchoring not just with a number but the same units as well (say currencies) should strengthen the effect.
  • We might hypothesize there is a model serving the notion of “estimation of numbers”, and that creates the expectation of a series of related tasks.  Changing estimation domains, such as predicting a non-numeric answer for the second task likely reduce the anchoring bias.


As HTM models can further inform and clarify how our minds engage these kinds of tasks, we expect them to also spur the development of new tools to help deliver information and inform decision making across a range of applications.
0 Comments

The Big (mis)Behavioral Arbitrage

3/3/2009

0 Comments

 

A great story in The (Mis)Behavior of Markets from Benoit Mandlebrot shines a floodlight on how broad the opportunities in Behavioral Arbitrage can be.  Evidently Warren Buffet once poked fun that he would like to fund even more university chairs in the classic Efficient Market Hypothesis, so they could train and send out even more mis-guided decision makers- whose money he could then proceed to take! 

Like any classical behavioral bias, a prevalent theory, particularly when it is a simplification of human behavior as Efficient Markets theory does, yet which becomes entrenched, dramatically shapes large group behaviors.  And in turn, this creates opportunities for those who can detect and design counter positions.

Our work in Behavioral Arbitrage, looking where deepset biases are in play, and developing ways to improve performance around them also applies of course to the financial markets.  Now if we could just capture more of Warren Buffett's intuitions!

0 Comments

    Archives

    October 2013
    August 2013
    May 2013
    March 2013
    June 2009
    March 2009
    February 2009
    December 2008
    November 2008

    Categories

    All
    About
    Anchoring
    Behavioral Analytics
    Behavioral Arbitrage
    Behavioral Finance
    Behavioral Marketing
    Curiosity
    Darwins Grove
    Empathy
    Marketing
    Openness
    Prospect Theory
    Viral Marketing

    RSS Feed


© 2014 Darwin's Grove LLC. All Rights Reserved.